Tyranny of numbers

Is inflation anti-poor in Iran?

Posted in Inequality, Macroeconomy by Djavad on June 9, 2010

This week Iran’s Central Bank announced that the annual inflation rate has dropped below 10%, so it may seem like an odd time to talk about how rising inflation might affect Iran’s poor.  But if the government implements the subsidy reform law, as it has promised to do in the second half of this year (Iranian year 1389), inflation will most likely rise.  The strongest objection to this reform is not that it will increase the rate of inflation, but that higher inflation will hurt the poor.  If that were to happen, it would be the height of irony, for the entire scheme was proposed to promote social justice, not to take money away from the poor.  From the point of view of social justice the best part of the scheme as it was originally proposed was that the rich would pay full price for energy and other basic goods while the poor received their subsidy as income.   With that scheme, the poor would have gained, at least in relative if not in absolute terms.  But the progressive cash-back scheme is no longer on the table, so the distributional effect of the subsidy reform very much depends on how inflation affects the poor versus the rich.  So, the crucial question is this: will the inflation that follows the removal of subsidies hurt the poor more than the rich?  I have not seen serious evidence that can answer this question (perhaps there is, but I have not seen any).  To satisfy my own curiosity I review here the historical evidence on inflation and equality, which seems to suggest that in Iran inflation may not be the cruelest tax of all, as the saying goes.

Figuring out whether the inflation that will follow the removal of subsidies is anti-poor is a complicated task. Raising energy prices alone will affect nearly all domestically produced goods and services and, depending on the energy intensity of the basket of consumption of the poor, it may hurt them more or less than the rich. It is technically feasible to model how prices will react to the removal of subsidies and how they affect the purchasing power of consumers in different income groups, which I am not prepared to undertake, so for the time being let us look at a simple correlation of inflation and the relative incomes of the poor versus the rich.

This graph depicts the rate of inflation and the ratio of mean per capita expenditures of the second poorest to the second richest decile (the same as the ratio of the shares of decile 2 to 9). I did not choose the first and the tenth deciles because survey data are less reliable at the two extremes.

The proportion of mean per capita expenditures of the 2nd to the 9th decile (right axis), and the annual rate of inflation (left axis).
Source: Author’s calculations from the Household Expenditures and Income Surveys 1984-2008, Statistical Center of Iran, and Central Bank of the Islamic Republic of Iran.

The co-movement of the two variables is quite noticeable in this graph (the simple correlation coefficient is 0.32), but of special interest is the behavior of the decile ratio in two inflationary periods.  The first is during 1991-1993, the period of taadil or structural adjustment, when the Rafsanjani government reduced war-time subsidies, let prices adjust to market demand and supply, and inflation soared.  Other things happened at the same time, like a sudden rise in oil income, so this is not exactly hypothesis testing, but the decile ratio moved in favor of the second lowest decile relative to the second highest.  As inflation eased, this ratio fell slightly. The second inflationary episode of interest is the inflation of the last few years, which was more decidedly oil-boom induced.   Again, other things happened that could have affected the distribution of income, but it is worth noting that this inflation, too, was also coincident with a rising share of the poor decile relative to the rich.

These observations do not mean that inflation does not seriously hurt some of the poor, or that the poor suffer less than the rich. Anyone with fixed income will lose when prices rise, and those at the bottom of the income distribution who lose will feel much greater pain than the losers from the top. Furthermore, at low income levels all expenditures are on necessities and, unlike the rich, the poor do not have luxuries to cut or assets to fall back on.  For these reasons, the poor rightly complain more loudly about inflation. 

Using polling data from 38 countries, Easterly and Fisher (Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 2001) found that the poor and the less educated express more concern for inflation than the rich and the more educated.  Interestingly, they also find that in the countries they study (Iran not included) the poor are not imagining things–they actually lose from inflation. 

Is this also the case in Iran?  Without further research it is hard to answer this question.  Every country is different in terms of the sources of income of its poor, the degree to which the incomes of the poor are indexed, and the level of social assistance that protects their consumption in bad times.  I have used expenditures here; it would interesting to repeat this exercise with income.  It is important to bear in mind that the poor are also sellers, for example of labor and farm products, and not just buyer, so they could potentially gain from rising prices.  In Iran unskilled wages seem to keep up with inflation (more on this at a later time).  In defense of posting this preliminary evidence I should say that my purpose is not to convince but to transform into question what appears in the Iranian public discourse to be a forgone conclusion, that inflation hurts the poor.

The more important influence on the lot of the poor in the case of Iran’s subsidy reform program is how the cash-back program will be implemented. We know that it lost much of its progressive thrust when the government abandoned its original progressive redistribution scheme in favor of a flat rebate. The government started with a costly effort to assess household wealth and income in order to distribute the proceeds from the reduction of subsidies to the poor, but the botched plan to divide the country into three groups (“khousheh“) seems to have killed that idea, at least for the time being.  The plan now seems to be for the government to disburse the money equally across poor and rich households, with a moral plea to the rich to voluntarily take their name out of the pool of recipients. I do not know how many Iranians have volunteered so far, besides the cabinet members I saw doing so on national television.  It would be a pity if some progressive scheme does not replace the stillborn “khousheh” plan.

About these ads

4 Responses

Subscribe to comments with RSS.

  1. Dr. Hamed H. said, on November 9, 2010 at 3:04 pm

    There is a reason why gov killed (hibernated) the Khosheh system. It was because of the possibility of political fall out specially in the face of increasing soft war propaganda beamed into Iran. But none theless when the subsidies are completely removed, Iran will surely will move in that direction as the subsidy cash payment to richer classes are slowly and painlessly removed year by year until only a social security kind of payment for only the poorest remains. But this all necessitates to institute a very precise wealth and tax reporting and collecting system in the country which currently is lacking. In fact in Iran hardly anyone files tax returns and those who do lie on their assets and incomes. It took west few centuries to make tax an integral part of western culture and in the beginning they had draconian laws in Europe as punishment for tax evasion. In England the punishment for tax evasion was death by hanging. So in light of these, it is not a question of whether Iran will ever be able to remove its subsidies but the real question is if Iran will ever be able to tax its rich fairly and if its rich accept the culture of tax forever as the rich in west have.

    • Djavad said, on November 13, 2010 at 8:31 am

      Thanks for your comment. I share your concern about taxation of income in Iran, which is both very low and is not progressive. Relative to advanced countries, Iran relies too much on corporate taxes, which are anti jobs, and on on sales taxes, which are regressive.

      I am not sure if the khousheh system was abandoned for political reasons originating from the outside. I think it failed in large part because it lacked credibility inside Iran. The designers tottally underestiamted its complexity.

  2. a said, on June 10, 2010 at 7:53 pm

    I don’t know if this is a good idea or not, but a campaign with the message that those who are receiving the cash-back money are “poor” can have a considerable effect. In a country where even people who are not reach try so hard to look as if they are reach, the social disadvantage of being called a relatively poor person because of receiving subsidies is not negligible. Announcing the names of people who are receiving these cash-backs can deter those people who want to look reach from receiving them.

    • Djavad said, on June 10, 2010 at 11:00 pm

      An interesting idea, shaming the rich, though I am not sure if it will go down well with most people to have their names announced.


Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s

Follow

Get every new post delivered to your Inbox.

Join 126 other followers

%d bloggers like this: